Asset Pricing in Emerging Markets

نویسندگان

  • Campbell R. Harvey
  • William Sharpe
  • Harry Markowitz
چکیده

Emerging markets provide a formidable challenge to current asset pricing theory. The reason that emerging market do not obey standard asset pricing paradigms can be traced to the lack of complete market integration of many of these markets. Importantly, to understand both the cross-section of expected returns as well as the evolution of expected returns through time in these markets, it is necessary to characterize the process of market integration. Markets that have undertaken substantial liberalization of their financial sectors to allow for the free flow of foreign portfolio investments tend to be more sensitive to the factors that may characterize a world asset pricing model. Asset pricing theory is a framework designed to identify and measure risk as well as assign rewards for risk bearing. This theory helps us understand why the expected return on a short-term government bond is a lot less than the expected return on a stock. Similarly, it helps us understand why two different stocks have different expected returns. The theory also helps us understand why expected returns change through time. The asset pricing framework usually begins with a number of premises such as: investors like higher rather than lower expected returns, investors dislike risk and investors hold well-diversified portfolios. These insights help us assess the “fair” rate of return for a particular asset. Such information is critical for the investment decision facing both corporations evaluating projects and investors forming portfolios. In the corporate setting, the theory helps us characterize the risk of a particular project or acquisition and assign a discount rate that reflects the risk. In choosing projects that have a higher promised rate of return than what would be assumed by the risk theory, corporations create value. In the portfolio investment setting, the theory helps us identify overvalued and undervalued assets. The theory is also integral in establishing a framework to help the investor understand the risk that he faces with a particular portfolio. The foundational work in asset pricing originated with Nobel Laureate William Sharpe (1964) and the late John Lintner (1965). While there have been many advances in asset pricing over the past 35 years, to understand the issues that we face with asset pricing in emerging markets, it is useful to follow the framework of the first asset pricing theory, the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) of Sharpe and Lintner. The key to understanding the complexities of emerging market asset pricing lies with the assumptions of the asset pricing theory. The CAPM suggests that investors hold well-diversified portfolios. Investors like higher expected returns and dislike variance. This is the framework pioneered by Nobel Laureate Harry Markowitz (1959). There is an important implication of the notion of well-diversified portfolios. The risk of the well-diversified portfolio is its variance – and the risk of a particular asset it not its own variance. The logic works as follows. You care about the variance of the portfolio – not of individual assets. A particular asset might have greater or lower variance than the portfolio. However, it does not make any sense to reward the asset based on its own variance. Correlation is the missing ingredient. It is possible that a very high variance asset can reduce the overall portfolio variance because it has low or negative correlation with the portfolio returns. Indeed, one can think of this high volatility asset with low correlation as providing insurance or hedging for the overall portfolio. Let’s follow this example further. Investor’s don’t like variance in their portfolio returns. The particular asset with high variance and low correlation is not judged on its own variance. It is judged on how it contributes to the variance of the well-diversified portfolio. In the example, it reduces the variance of the portfolio. As a result, this asset is valuable (investors like variance reducing assets) and the expected return as a result is low. In other words, because investors value the variance reducing properties of this asset in the context of their portfolio, the price is bid up to the point that the future expected returns are low. So, to be clear here, it is possible that a high volatility asset has a low expected return and it is also possible that the high volatility asset has a high expected return. It is not the variance of the asset that matters – it is the contribution to the variance of the portfolio. This contribution is the covariance. The model of Sharpe (1964) and Lintner (1965) formalize this. Expected returns on asset are different because the assets have different covariances with a well-diversified portfolio. The model also includes a reward for covariance risk. That is, in order to translate the covariance into expected return, we need the price of covariance risk – how this risk is treated in the marketplace. There are numerous ways to derive the CAPM and we will not go into the different ways. However, some of the most important assumptions are: investors only care about mean and variance, asset returns are multivariate normally distributed (or equivalent assumptions on investor utility could be made to replace this assumption), capital markets are perfect (all information is correctly reflected in prices as in Fama (1970), there are no transactions costs, no taxes, etc.), there are no disagreements about the returns distributions. All of these assumptions are counterfactual. However, they provide a framework to derive a simple model that has rich implications. One serious problem in applying this model to international finance is the assumption of perfect capital markets. In an international setting, this assumption also means that markets are perfectly integrated. This means the following: the same risk asset commands the same expected return regardless of location (country). A sufficient condition for this to work is that there are no effective barriers to portfolio investment across borders. That is, local investors are free to add any stock in the world to their portfolio and international investors are free to choose any stock within a particular country. With capital market integration, we get a world version of the Capital Asset Pricing Model. That is, assets within a particular country are rewarded in terms of their contribution to a well-diversified world portfolio. What matters is the covariance with the world portfolio. There is also a world price of covariance risk that translates the contribution into expected returns. The world price is directly linked to the weighted average risk aversion in the world. Higher risk aversion implies a higher world price of covariance risk. The world CAPM is a powerful model and has met with some success in being applied to developed market returns [see Harvey (1991)]. However, the same model fails when applied to emerging market returns [see Harvey (1995)]. There are many reasons why the model fails in emerging markets – but a leading and logical candidate is the lack of market integration in some emerging markets. To understand the impact of market integration, consider a completely segmented (nonintegrated) country. In this country, local investors are not allowed to own foreign securities. Foreign investors are not allowed to own local securities. If the CAPM held in this segmented country, then the relevant risk that investors face is the asset’s contribution to variance of a diversified portfolio within the particular country – not the world. The risk that investors face is the variance of the country portfolio. Let us make the distinction clear here. In the integrated world, a country portfolio’s risk is its covariance with world returns. This covariance is rewarded with a common world price which is linked to weighted average risk aversion in the world. In the segmented world, a country portfolio’s risk is it variance. The variance is rewarded with a country specific price which is linked to a weighted average risk aversion within the particular country. These scenarios, integrated/segmented are polar extremes. Early capital markets research on emerging markets recognized the importance of market integration and realized that it was likely that many markets were not completely integrated into world capital markets but they were not completely segmented either. For example, Errunza and Losq (1985) proposed a model of partial integration. Roughly speaking, one could think of expected returns in a partially segmented emerging market as reflecting some reward for the covariance with world returns as well as some reward for the market’s own variance. One gets a hybrid CAPM that includes both variance as well as covariance with the world. Bekaert and Harvey (1995) critique the usual implementation of the partial integration/segmentation model. The traditional model assumes that the degree of integration/segmentation is fixed over time. However, this flies in the face of substantial liberalizations of equity markets in many emerging countries in the late 1980s. That is, the traditional framework does not handle the dynamics of capital market integration. Bekaert and Harvey (1995) present an alternative framework for the valuation of emerging market assets. This framework explicitly recognizes that the integration process is gradual. Bekaert and Harvey parameterize and estimate a model that allows for a timevarying market integration. In the polar case of market integration, their model reduces to the world capital asset pricing model. In the case of market segmentation, their model reduces to a local CAPM. In the partial integration world, the expected rate of return is a weighting of world covariance times world price of covariance risk and the local volatility and the reward for the local volatility. To make the model dynamic, this weighting changes through time. The model assumes that the weighting is function of two variables that proxy for the openness of the market: the size of the trade sector and the capitalization of the local equity market. What happens when an emerging market liberalizes and becomes more integrated into world capital markets? This is a growing area of research that sheds much light on asset pricing in emerging markets. We will first consider what the theory suggests and second consider the evidence. As mentioned above, in the segmented capital market, variance counts. In addition, the variance of the country portfolio is high (because it is not a truly diversified portfolio in a world context). To make matters worse, many emerging markets do not have the breadth of industrial sectors that developed countries have. That is, the firms come from very few industries. Further, most of the local firms’ prospects are tied to the local economy. As a result, the returns of these firms tend to move in the same direction on any given day. This is another reason why variance is so high in segmented markets. Expected returns are also high. The local investors do not want to bear this extreme volatility. However, local corporations need to raise funds for investment projects. In order to get local investors to purchase local equity, the price must be low (expected rewards must be high). A subsidiary, but important, point is that local corporations decline to pursue a number of seemingly profitable capital projects because the cost of equity capital is so high. For example, a project might promise a 25% rate of return which is extraordinary in the context of developed markets. However, this project might be rejected because the cost of equity capital is 30%. Now consider the integration process. Suppose regulations are changed such that local investors can purchase stocks outside their country and foreigners are allowed into the local market. The most important impact will come from foreigners. They will be attracted to the emerging market for two reasons. First, at current values, the prices are cheap and the expected returns are high compared to what could be earned in developed markets. Second, because of the different industrial compositions of emerging markets relative to developed markets, the correlation of these markets’ returns with world returns is lower than the correlation of developed markets’ returns with world returns. This last point is important. Even though the volatility of the individual emerging market is high, the correlations are low or negative which implies that the addition of emerging markets to a well-diversified world portfolio could reduce portfolio volatility. When the foreign investors pour into the market to take advantage of the low correlation/high expected return opportunities, prices rise and expected returns decrease. So, one immediate implication of capital market liberalization is that expected returns should decrease. Remember that the expected returns started out from quite a high level. There is plenty of room for the expected returns to decrease. Bekaert and Harvey (2000) and Henry (2000) document this phenomena. Bekaert and Harvey propose a set of dates that reflect capital market liberalization. They find that the expected returns decrease after liberalizations. There are powerful implications to the decrease in expected returns. An immediate implication is that the cost of equity capital decreases. For local firms, this means that the investment projects that, in the past, were rejected because of expensive equity financing – are now profitable. We would expect to see an increase in capital investment as a proportion to GDP with a decrease in the cost of capital. We would also expect to see high GDP growth. The evidence in Bekeart, Harvey and Lundblad (2000) provides convincing evidence in favor of these implications. In a cross-country study of the determinants of GDP growth, Bekaert, Harvey and Lundblad find that liberalization of capital market leads to a 1.5% increase in real GDP growth. There are other potential implications of capital market liberalization. Policy makers, in particular, are often concerned with the volatility of capital market returns. Is it the case that liberalization or the move to more integrated capital markets increases local equity volatility? In the case of volatility, there are many possible theories. It might be that capital market integration brings new trading volume and many new analysts watching emerging market stocks thereby increasing the informational efficiency. As a result, these stocks react faster to relevant information and we may see a natural increase in volatility. Volatility might also increase as so-called “hot” foreign portfolio investment is withdrawn from a particular country on the hint of economic/financial/political unrest. Volatility may also increase as local firms specialize their product line to focus on the goods that they have a demonstrable competitive advantage in producing. There are reasons for volatility to decrease too. Financial integration is often accompanied or preceded by economic integration. As firms trade their goods and services in world markets, they become less susceptible to shocks or economic fluctuations from the local economy. That is, world trade provides a natural economic hedge. Less sensitivity to the local economy can reasonably be translated into lower volatility of equity returns. The evidence presented in Bekaert and Harvey (1997, 2000) suggests that there is no significant impact on volatility. Market integration sometimes leads to higher volatility and sometimes leads to lower volatility – it depends on the country. This ambiguous result is consistent with the different theories of volatility. What about correlation with world returns? Historically, many researchers have looked at increases in correlation as evidence of capital market integration. However, this approach is potentially flawed. Two countries may be completely integrated and, at the same time, their equity returns are uncorrelated. The low correlation could simply reflect the different industrial mixes in the two countries. The argument articulated above that local companies might find more of their business in world product markets is a powerful reason why correlations may increase. In an integrated world, local companies will be influenced by the same type of world shocks that companies in developed markets experience. For example, if the U.S. falls into recession, this is bad news for many stocks in developed countries because the U.S. is a major consumer of their goods. While segmented, the local economy may have been largely shielded from such fluctuations. However, as both the economic and financial integration process is initiated, local companies could be very much affected by, for example, a U.S. recession. Correlations should increase as a result. The evidence in Bekaert and Harvey (2000) suggest that correlations increase after financial liberalizations. Note that one of the important reasons for foreign investors to enter these emerging markets and purchase securities is the low correlation. Importantly, the evidence in Bekaert and Harvey does not suggest that the diversification potential is eliminated. Even the new higher level of correlation provides substantial benefits to international diversification and is well below the threshold level set by developed markets. For asset pricing theory, it is critical to know when and if an emerging market has effectively liberalized. Notice the use of the word “effective”. Bekaert and Harvey (1995) argue that a country might be liberalized to the letter of the law but effectively segmented. That is, new laws might be passed that make it easier for foreigners to access the local capital markets – but it is possible that no foreigners bother to enter the market. This might happen if the liberalization was not credible – or if there was a threat of future policy makers reversing the liberalizations. Conversely, it is possible, by the letter of the law, that a country appears completely segmented but it effectively integrated. Indeed, the growth of country closed-end funds as well as American Depository Receipts (ADRs) has made it possible for foreign investors to access local securities without directly purchasing the securities on the local market (where they might not be allowed to transact). So, it is potentially problematic to judge the degree of integration by looking at particular regulations. The analysis in Bekaert and Harvey (2000) considers a number of different dating schemes: regulatory, introduction of first ADR, introduction of country fund, and a composite indicator of the first sign of liberalization (first date of regulatory, ADR and country fund). Bekaert and Harvey also examine U.S. portfolio flows. Indeed, if the market is truly open, then supporting evidence of integration would be a dramatic pickup in foreign portfolio flows to the emerging market. The idea of portfolio flows as a proxy for market integration is analyzed in Bekaert, Harvey and Lumsdaine (2000a). Using the econometrics of break point analysis, they examine the interrelationship between capital flows and expected returns in emerging markets. Indeed, it is possible that a number of financial and economic variables are fundamentally impacted by the market integration process. Bekaert, Harvey and Lumsdaine (2000b) present the first multivariate tests that try to date the integration of world capital markets. The idea of this paper is to let the data speak for itself. They simultaneously examine a number of important aggregates and use endogenous break point analysis reveal the common break point. They link this break point to capital market liberalization. For example, we expect to see a decrease in the cost of capital and an increase in foreign portfolio flows. The technology in this paper uses the information in many different economic aggregate series to come up with a composite break point. The analysis in Bekaert and Harvey (2000) as well as Bekaert, Harvey and Lumsdaine (2000a,b) suggests that many of emerging markets have successfully liberalized their capital markets. There is a clustering of liberalizations in the late 1980s and early 1990s. This suggests that it is more likely that some version of the world capital asset pricing model holds today than 10 years ago for emerging markets. This is consistent with the results presented in Harvey (2000) who studies the ability of a world version of the CAPM to explain expected returns in 20 developed markets and 27 emerging markets. There is one additional important issue. Traditional asset pricing theory operates in a world of mean and variance. The assumption of multivariate normality is often invoked. However, the evidence in Bekaert and Harvey (1997) strongly suggests that emerging market returns are highly non-normal. There is also evidence that the returns many developed countries are non-normal. In addition, there is considerable discussion of the “downside risks” of investing in emerging markets. That is, emerging markets are known to suffer from sharp crises. Two recent memories are the Mexican crisis of December 1994 and the Asian crisis of July 1997. The analysis of downside can be handled within the traditional asset pricing frameworks. For example, Rubinstein (1973) and Kraus and Litzenberger (1976) developed an asset pricing framework that explicitly considers the skewness of portfolio returns. Harvey and Siddique (2000) present tests of an asset-pricing model with a dynamic measure of skewness. The logic of these models is much like that of the CAPM – indeed, it is a straightforward extension of the CAPM. Investor like expected returns, dislike variance, and dislike negative skewness (but like positive skewness). Investors’ preference for positive skewness is evidenced by the unusually high price that they will pay for a lottery ticket (which has an expected return of –50%). We also see evidence in the options markets where put options on the S&P index have very high prices. Investors are using these put options to protect against extreme downside moves in the equity market. These options reduce negative skewness in an investor’s portfolio. As a result, they are valuable (high price). Like variance, it is not the skewness of the particular asset that matters – it is the contribution of that asset to the portfolio’s skewness. This is called the coskewness. If the coskewness is negative, it means that the asset is contributing negative skewness to the portfolio. In order to get people to purchase an asset with such an undesirable property, the price must be low (expected returns high). If the asset offers to increase the portfolio skewness (which is desirable), the price will be bid upwards (expected returns will be low). Harvey and Siddique (2000) present tests of an asset pricing model that incorporates skewness. They find some success in explaining the cross-section of U.S. equity returns with this framework. Harvey (2000) looks at a model with skewness for 47 international stock markets. His analysis is broken into three groups: developed countries, emerging markets and all countries. He only considers data from 1988 which marks the beginning of an intense period of capital market reforms in emerging markets. If markets were completely segmented, then what counts is the country’s variance and total skewness. If markets are completely integrated, what counts is the covariance and coskewness. Harvey presents evidence that developed markets are not impacted by variance and total skewness, which is consistent with them being integrated. Evidence is also presented that covariance and coskewness do a reasonable job in emerging markets as well – suggesting that many of these markets have successfully integrated into world capital markets. However, his evidence suggests that these emerging markets are not completely integrated. In some of his tests, both variance and total skewness provide incremental ability to explain the cross-section of expected returns in emerging markets. The evidence suggests that it is unwise to assume that emerging markets are fully integrated into world capital markets. There are a host of additional issues that we face in investing in emerging markets. Transactions costs (execution fees, bid-ask spread and market impact) are higher than developed markets. Accute information asymmetries can exist (local investors may have better information than foreign investors). Regulations, such as insider trading laws, may not exist or even if they exist are not enforced. Many securities suffer from chronic infrequent trading making the price data unreliable. There is also the general issue as to how to handle foreign currency risk within asset pricing theory [see Dumas and Solnik (1995) as well as the early work of Solnik (1974) and Stulz (1981)]. Each of these additional issues increases the probability that standard asset pricing models will fail when applied to emerging markets. Finally, there is one overriding issue that impacts the study of asset pricing in emerging markets – as well as a more general study of asset pricing. It is not clear that the standard models are adequate to capture the complexities of security valuation in developed markets let alone emerging markets. Recently, in a number of studies of U.S. equity returns, the traditional CAPM has come under attack. Indeed, most view the U.S. market as one of the most efficient markets in the world, which would maximize the chance that the CAPM would work. However, the international evidence is more generous to the traditional framework. It is paramount to explicitly allow for the role of capital market integration. After doing so, the tradition frameworks, perhaps augmented with measures of coskewness are able to do a reasonable job in explaining the cross-section of expected returns.

برای دانلود متن کامل این مقاله و بیش از 32 میلیون مقاله دیگر ابتدا ثبت نام کنید

ثبت نام

اگر عضو سایت هستید لطفا وارد حساب کاربری خود شوید

منابع مشابه

Market integration in developed and emerging markets: Evidence from the CAPM

Beta, as measured by the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), is widely used for pricing stocks, determining the cost of capital, and gauging the extent to which markets are integrated. The CAPM model assumes that equilibrium conditions prevail. The choice of which market portfolio to use in the regression – the home country or global index – depends on the level of global market integration. We...

متن کامل

Testing Conditional Asset Pricing Models: An Emerging Market Perspective

The CAPM as the benchmark asset pricing model generally performs poorly in both developed and emerging markets. We investigate whether allowing the model parameters to vary improves the performance of the CAPM and the Fama-French model. Conditional asset pricing models scaled by conditional variables such as Trading Volume and Dividend Yield generally result in small pricing errors. However, a ...

متن کامل

Optimizing Financial Asset Pricing Using Quantitative Behavioral Bias Measurement

Optimization of pricing financial assets less an emerging discipline that attempts to model the impact of biases that investors in asset prices. This article provides an overview of the theoretical foundations and challenges and offers some solutions in this field. The paper is divided into two parts. In the first part of the paper, an overview of the selected literature is presented on key the...

متن کامل

Examination‌ of Equity Premium Puzzle by Consumption Capital Asset Pricing Model with Fuzzy Nested Regimes: Evidence from Iran

The aim of this study is to examine the equity premium puzzle in Iran for the quarterly period of 1993-2016. In this regard, the hybrid bivariate Garch model and also fuzzy dummy variables with consumption capital asset pricing model (C-CAPM) have been used. The results of study show that using C-CAPM within fuzzy dummy variables (CCAPM-F), the relative risk aversion coefficient of investor is ...

متن کامل

‘Market Liquidity and Stock Size Premia in Emerging Financial Markets: The Implications for Foreign Investment ’

Equity markets are increasingly seen as important sources of investment funds in many emerging economies. Furthermore, many countries see the development of such markets as a means to facilitate both foreign equity portfolio investment and foreign direct investment (FDI). This may occur through acquisition of shareholdings in domestic companies, which supplements the low levels of funding from ...

متن کامل

ذخیره در منابع من


  با ذخیره ی این منبع در منابع من، دسترسی به آن را برای استفاده های بعدی آسان تر کنید

برای دانلود متن کامل این مقاله و بیش از 32 میلیون مقاله دیگر ابتدا ثبت نام کنید

ثبت نام

اگر عضو سایت هستید لطفا وارد حساب کاربری خود شوید

عنوان ژورنال:

دوره   شماره 

صفحات  -

تاریخ انتشار 2000